forked from enterstudio/wp-static
-
Notifications
You must be signed in to change notification settings - Fork 0
/
Copy pathcarbon-price.html
529 lines (53 loc) · 76.1 KB
/
carbon-price.html
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
61
62
63
64
65
66
67
68
69
70
71
72
73
74
75
76
77
78
79
80
81
82
83
84
85
86
87
88
89
90
91
92
93
94
95
96
97
98
99
100
101
102
103
104
105
106
107
108
109
110
111
112
113
114
115
116
117
118
119
120
121
122
123
124
125
126
127
128
129
130
131
132
133
134
135
136
137
138
139
140
141
142
143
144
145
146
147
148
149
150
151
152
153
154
155
156
157
158
159
160
161
162
163
164
165
166
167
168
169
170
171
172
173
174
175
176
177
178
179
180
181
182
183
184
185
186
187
188
189
190
191
192
193
194
195
196
197
198
199
200
201
202
203
204
205
206
207
208
209
210
211
212
213
214
215
216
217
218
219
220
221
222
223
224
225
226
227
228
229
230
231
232
233
234
235
236
237
238
239
240
241
242
243
244
245
246
247
248
249
250
251
252
253
254
255
256
257
258
259
260
261
262
263
264
265
266
267
268
269
270
271
272
273
274
275
276
277
278
279
280
281
282
283
284
285
286
287
288
289
290
291
292
293
294
295
296
297
298
299
300
301
302
303
304
305
306
307
308
309
310
311
312
313
314
315
316
317
318
319
320
321
322
323
324
325
326
327
328
329
330
331
332
333
334
335
336
337
338
339
340
341
342
343
344
345
346
347
348
349
350
351
352
353
354
355
356
357
358
359
360
361
362
363
364
365
366
367
368
369
370
371
372
373
374
375
376
377
378
379
380
381
382
383
384
385
386
387
388
389
390
391
392
393
394
395
396
397
398
399
400
401
402
403
404
405
406
407
408
409
410
411
412
413
414
415
416
417
418
419
420
421
422
423
424
425
426
427
428
429
430
431
432
433
434
435
436
437
438
439
440
441
442
443
444
445
446
447
448
449
450
451
452
453
454
455
456
457
458
459
460
461
462
463
464
465
466
467
468
469
470
471
472
473
474
475
476
477
478
479
480
481
482
483
484
485
486
487
488
489
490
491
492
493
494
495
496
497
498
499
500
501
502
503
504
505
506
507
508
509
510
511
512
513
514
515
516
517
518
519
520
521
522
523
524
525
526
527
528
529
<!doctype html><html><head><meta name="viewport" content="width=device-width, initial-scale=1"/><title>The argument for a carbon price - Our World in Data</title><meta name="description" content="We are paying a price for fossil fuels, but that price is not paid by those that burn the fossil fuels – we need to change that."/><link rel="canonical" href="https://ourworldindata.org/carbon-price"/><link rel="alternate" type="application/atom+xml" href="/atom.xml"/><link rel="apple-touch-icon" sizes="180x180" href="/apple-touch-icon.png"/><meta property="fb:app_id" content="1149943818390250"/><meta property="og:url" content="https://ourworldindata.org/carbon-price"/><meta property="og:title" content="The argument for a carbon price"/><meta property="og:description" content="We are paying a price for fossil fuels, but that price is not paid by those that burn the fossil fuels – we need to change that."/><meta property="og:image" content="https://ourworldindata.org/app/uploads/2021/05/Screen-Shot-2021-05-31-at-21.19.57-768x344.png"/><meta property="og:site_name" content="Our World in Data"/><meta name="twitter:card" content="summary_large_image"/><meta name="twitter:site" content="@OurWorldInData"/><meta name="twitter:creator" content="@OurWorldInData"/><meta name="twitter:title" content="The argument for a carbon price"/><meta name="twitter:description" content="We are paying a price for fossil fuels, but that price is not paid by those that burn the fossil fuels – we need to change that."/><meta name="twitter:image" content="https://ourworldindata.org/app/uploads/2021/05/Screen-Shot-2021-05-31-at-21.19.57-768x344.png"/><link href="https://fonts.googleapis.com/css?family=Lato:300,400,400i,700,700i|Playfair+Display:400,700&display=swap" rel="stylesheet"/><link rel="stylesheet" href="https://ourworldindata.org/assets/commons.css"/><link rel="stylesheet" href="https://ourworldindata.org/assets/owid.css"/></head><body class=""><header class="site-header"><div class="wrapper site-navigation-bar"><div class="site-logo"><a href="/">Our World<br/> in Data</a></div><nav class="site-navigation"><div class="topics-button-wrapper"><a href="/#entries" class="topics-button"><div class="label">Articles <br/><strong>by topic</strong></div><div class="icon"><svg width="12" height="6"><path d="M0,0 L12,0 L6,6 Z" fill="currentColor"></path></svg></div></a></div><div><div class="site-primary-navigation"><form class="HeaderSearch" action="/search" method="GET"><input type="search" name="q" placeholder="Search..."/><div class="icon"><svg aria-hidden="true" focusable="false" data-prefix="fas" data-icon="magnifying-glass" class="svg-inline--fa fa-magnifying-glass " role="img" xmlns="http://www.w3.org/2000/svg" viewBox="0 0 512 512"><path fill="currentColor" d="M500.3 443.7l-119.7-119.7c27.22-40.41 40.65-90.9 33.46-144.7C401.8 87.79 326.8 13.32 235.2 1.723C99.01-15.51-15.51 99.01 1.724 235.2c11.6 91.64 86.08 166.7 177.6 178.9c53.8 7.189 104.3-6.236 144.7-33.46l119.7 119.7c15.62 15.62 40.95 15.62 56.57 0C515.9 484.7 515.9 459.3 500.3 443.7zM79.1 208c0-70.58 57.42-128 128-128s128 57.42 128 128c0 70.58-57.42 128-128 128S79.1 278.6 79.1 208z"></path></svg></div></form><ul class="site-primary-links"><li><a href="/blog" data-track-note="header-navigation">Latest</a></li><li><a href="/about" data-track-note="header-navigation">About</a></li><li><a href="/donate" data-track-note="header-navigation">Donate</a></li></ul></div><div class="site-secondary-navigation"><ul class="site-secondary-links"><li><a href="/charts" data-track-note="header-navigation">All charts</a></li><li><a href="https://sdg-tracker.org" data-track-note="header-navigation">Sustainable Development Goals Tracker</a></li></ul></div></div></nav><div class="header-logos-wrapper"><a href="https://www.oxfordmartin.ox.ac.uk/global-development" class="oxford-logo"><img src="https://ourworldindata.org/oms-logo.svg" alt="Oxford Martin School logo"/></a><a href="https://global-change-data-lab.org/" class="gcdl-logo"><img src="https://ourworldindata.org/gcdl-logo.svg" alt="Global Change Data Lab logo"/></a></div><div class="mobile-site-navigation"><button data-track-note="mobile-search-button"><svg aria-hidden="true" focusable="false" data-prefix="fas" data-icon="magnifying-glass" class="svg-inline--fa fa-magnifying-glass " role="img" xmlns="http://www.w3.org/2000/svg" viewBox="0 0 512 512"><path fill="currentColor" d="M500.3 443.7l-119.7-119.7c27.22-40.41 40.65-90.9 33.46-144.7C401.8 87.79 326.8 13.32 235.2 1.723C99.01-15.51-15.51 99.01 1.724 235.2c11.6 91.64 86.08 166.7 177.6 178.9c53.8 7.189 104.3-6.236 144.7-33.46l119.7 119.7c15.62 15.62 40.95 15.62 56.57 0C515.9 484.7 515.9 459.3 500.3 443.7zM79.1 208c0-70.58 57.42-128 128-128s128 57.42 128 128c0 70.58-57.42 128-128 128S79.1 278.6 79.1 208z"></path></svg></button><button data-track-note="mobile-newsletter-button"><svg aria-hidden="true" focusable="false" data-prefix="fas" data-icon="envelope-open-text" class="svg-inline--fa fa-envelope-open-text " role="img" xmlns="http://www.w3.org/2000/svg" viewBox="0 0 512 512"><path fill="currentColor" d="M256 417.1c-16.38 0-32.88-4.1-46.88-15.12L0 250.9v213.1C0 490.5 21.5 512 48 512h416c26.5 0 48-21.5 48-47.1V250.9l-209.1 151.1C288.9 412 272.4 417.1 256 417.1zM493.6 163C484.8 156 476.4 149.5 464 140.1v-44.12c0-26.5-21.5-48-48-48l-77.5 .0016c-3.125-2.25-5.875-4.25-9.125-6.5C312.6 29.13 279.3-.3732 256 .0018C232.8-.3732 199.4 29.13 182.6 41.5c-3.25 2.25-6 4.25-9.125 6.5L96 48c-26.5 0-48 21.5-48 48v44.12C35.63 149.5 27.25 156 18.38 163C6.75 172 0 186 0 200.8v10.62l96 69.37V96h320v184.7l96-69.37V200.8C512 186 505.3 172 493.6 163zM176 255.1h160c8.836 0 16-7.164 16-15.1c0-8.838-7.164-16-16-16h-160c-8.836 0-16 7.162-16 16C160 248.8 167.2 255.1 176 255.1zM176 191.1h160c8.836 0 16-7.164 16-16c0-8.838-7.164-15.1-16-15.1h-160c-8.836 0-16 7.162-16 15.1C160 184.8 167.2 191.1 176 191.1z"></path></svg></button><button data-track-note="mobile-hamburger-button"><svg aria-hidden="true" focusable="false" data-prefix="fas" data-icon="bars" class="svg-inline--fa fa-bars " role="img" xmlns="http://www.w3.org/2000/svg" viewBox="0 0 448 512"><path fill="currentColor" d="M0 96C0 78.33 14.33 64 32 64H416C433.7 64 448 78.33 448 96C448 113.7 433.7 128 416 128H32C14.33 128 0 113.7 0 96zM0 256C0 238.3 14.33 224 32 224H416C433.7 224 448 238.3 448 256C448 273.7 433.7 288 416 288H32C14.33 288 0 273.7 0 256zM416 448H32C14.33 448 0 433.7 0 416C0 398.3 14.33 384 32 384H416C433.7 384 448 398.3 448 416C448 433.7 433.7 448 416 448z"></path></svg></button></div></div></header><div class="alert-banner"><div class="content"><div class="text"><strong>COVID-19 vaccinations, cases, excess mortality, and much more</strong></div><a href="/coronavirus#explore-the-global-situation" data-track-note="covid-banner-click">Explore our COVID-19 data</a></div></div><main><article class="page no-sidebar thin-banner"><div class="offset-header"><header class="article-header"><div class="article-titles"><h1 class="entry-title">The argument for a carbon price</h1></div></header></div><div class="content-wrapper"><div class="offset-content"><div class="content-and-footnotes"><div class="article-content"><section><div class="wp-block-columns is-style-sticky-right"><div class="wp-block-column"><div class="article-meta"><div class="excerpt">We are paying a price for fossil fuels, but that price is not paid by those that burn the fossil fuels – we need to change that.</div><div class="authors-byline"><a href="/team">by Max Roser</a></div><div class="published-updated"><time>June 01, 2021</time></div></div><div class="wp-block-owid-summary">
<h2 id="summary">Summary<a class="deep-link" href="#summary"></a></h2>
<p>It is a mistake to believe that we are not paying for emitting greenhouse gases. Even if we do not pay a <em>monetary</em> price for carbon emissions we do pay a very large price, the consequences of climate change.</p>
<p>Without a monetary carbon price it is those who have the smallest emissions that suffer the largest costs from climate change. A carbon price, in contrast, means that those who cause the emissions also pay for them.</p>
<p>A key reason why voters are not in favour of carbon pricing is that many believe it won’t actually reduce emissions, but empirical research and theory show that this is wrong: pricing carbon emissions – either via a carbon tax or a ‘cap and trade’-system – is effective. It shifts production and consumption from carbon-intensive goods and services to low-carbon alternatives and does reduce emissions.</p>
<p>Many are deeply concerned about climate change yet feel hopeless that anything can be done to meet this challenge. Increasing the understanding that carbon pricing works, correcting common misconceptions, and showing that there <em>is</em> a way forward are key steps for a successful fight against climate change.</p>
<p>I believe a carbon price should be complemented by other policies and in this article I make the case that it is one of the most important policy options we have to achieve a better future.</p>
</div><p>We are paying a price for burning fossil fuels and emitting greenhouse gases.</p><p>Some of the consequences of climate change are already visible today, but the most severe consequences will hit us in the years and decades to come:<a id="ref-1" class="ref" href="#note-1"><sup>1</sup></a></p><p>These consequences include the negative economic impacts of climate change through its effects on people’s livelihoods, and the damage to infrastructure through rising sea levels, thawing permafrost, and extreme weather events. They pose a large threat to the life of animals and ecosystems on our planet and include the destruction of coral reefs, forest fires, the loss of ice shields, and the expansion of deserts. They include an increase in extreme weather events, like heat waves, droughts, floods, and storms. And especially for <a href="https://ourworldindata.org/extreme-poverty" data-type="page" data-id="1701">the world’s poorest people</a> they pose a threat to their lives, as they increase the risk of hunger and food insecurity.</p><p>Climate change isn’t the only negative consequence of burning fossil fuels. The air pollution that is caused by burning fossil fuels kills an estimated 3.6 million people in <a href="https://ourworldindata.org/grapher/pollution-deaths-from-fossil-fuels?stackMode=absolute&region=World">countries around the world</a> every year; this is 6-times the annual death toll of all murders, war deaths, and terrorist attacks combined.<a id="ref-2" class="ref" href="#note-2"><sup>2</sup></a></p><p><em>This</em> is the price we are <em>already</em> paying for burning fossil fuels.</p><p>The International Monetary Fund (IMF) estimates the sum of these costs in a major study that they update regularly. The title of the study is <em>‘How Large Are Global Fossil Fuel Subsidies?’</em> and in the study’s latest issue the researchers estimate them to amount to US-$ 5.2 trillion.<a id="ref-3" class="ref" href="#note-3"><sup>3</sup></a> This is equivalent to 6.5% of global GDP.</p><p>As the study’s title makes clear, the IMF sees the sum of damage done by fossil fuels as a <em>subsidy</em>. That might be surprising at first, but it makes sense if you think about it. A good is subsidized when consumers and producers of that good do not have to pay the full cost for it. This can either be an <em>explicit subsidy</em>, for example when governments pay for the school education of the country’s children, or it can be an <em>implicit subsidy</em>, when producers and consumers cause damage, but do not have to pay a monetary price for it.<a id="ref-4" class="ref" href="#note-4"><sup>4</sup></a></p><p>You find examples of both types of subsidies in your own life. If you pay for you and your neighbour’s dinner then you are <em>explicitly </em>subsidizing them. If your neighbour crashes into your car and you do not charge him for the damage he caused, you are <em>implicitly </em>subsidizing them.</p><p>Fossil fuels are subsidized in both ways. They are <a href="https://ourworldindata.org/grapher/fossil-fuel-subsidies-per-capita?time=2015">explicitly subsidized in many places</a>, and they are implicitly subsidized <em>everywhere</em>, as the consumers and producers of fossil fuels do not have to pay the monetary cost for the damage they cause.</p><p>Ending the subsidies to fossil fuels would mean to put a monetary price on them that corresponds to the damage they do. Since the alternatives to fossil fuels are both <a href="https://ourworldindata.org/safest-sources-of-energy">cleaner and safer</a> this would allow the world to make massive progress according to the IMF study: Ending these subsidies and pricing them into the cost that producers and consumers have to pay for fossil fuels would substantially decrease global carbon emissions and save the lives of people who would otherwise be killed by air pollution.<a id="ref-5" class="ref" href="#note-5"><sup>5</sup></a></p><p>The damage caused by burning fossil fuels is a textbook example of what economists call an externality: Putting a monetary price on carbon emissions makes it possible to internalize the costs of the negative impact on our health, the environment, and future generations.<a id="ref-6" class="ref" href="#note-6"><sup>6</sup></a></p></div><div class="wp-block-column"></div></div><div class="wp-block-columns is-style-sticky-right"><div class="wp-block-column"><h4 id="this-means-that-we-do-not-have-the-option-to-not-pay-a-price">This means that we do not have the option to not pay a price<a class="deep-link" href="#this-means-that-we-do-not-have-the-option-to-not-pay-a-price"></a></h4></div><div class="wp-block-column"></div></div><div class="wp-block-columns is-style-sticky-right"><div class="wp-block-column"><p>It is a mistake to think that it is possible to not pay for emitting carbon. As we have just seen, <em>we </em><strong><em>are</em></strong><em> already paying a price</em>. </p><p>This is the economists’ argument for putting an explicit monetary price on carbon emissions.</p><h5>What would change if we put a monetary price on carbon?</h5><p>There are two ways in which a carbon price can be implemented: a carbon tax or a ‘cap and trade’ system:<a id="ref-7" class="ref" href="#note-7"><sup>7</sup></a> </p><ul><li>In a ‘cap and trade’ system the carbon price changes over time. A maximum level of pollution (a ‘cap’) is defined and manufacturers need licenses to emit carbon. How expensive these licenses are is determined by a trading system. The price of a license increases as emissions approach the cap. </li><li>A carbon tax is simply a levy that is applied to all goods and services which lead to carbon emissions in their production.</li></ul><p>In both systems the price of any product increases with the amount of carbon emitted in the production of it. The result is that products with a low carbon footprint (like taking the train or solar energy) do not get more expensive, while goods that do create a lot of emissions (like a flight or coal energy) do get more expensive.</p><p>This helps us reduce emissions and pollution in two ways: it makes carbon-intensive goods much more expensive, meaning consumers will opt for cheaper low-carbon alternatives when they are available; and in markets where they’re not available yet producers will be incentivised to develop low-carbon alternatives.</p><p>Carbon pricing changes the relative prices between carbon-intensive and low-carbon products and this changes consumption choices towards a low-carbon lifestyle: Carbon prices make it more likely that we rely on low-carbon electricity rather than fossil fuels; that we take the bicycle rather than the car; that we buy the smaller car rather than the bigger one; that we buy electric vehicles rather than gas-powered ones; that we eat <a href="https://ourworldindata.org/food-choice-vs-eating-local">chicken rather than beef</a>; or that we organize a video conference rather than an event that is a flight away. </p><p>Both of the intended consequences – transition to and innovation of alternative low-carbon technologies – increase with the carbon price. The incentive for consumers and entrepreneurs is to reduce their emissions whenever doing so costs them less than paying the carbon price. </p><p>Because access to energy often constitutes a large share of the budget of poorer families, successful carbon pricing policies include support for those households to offset the increased cost of energy.<a id="ref-8" class="ref" href="#note-8"><sup>8</sup></a></p><p>In the case of a carbon tax, the government revenue can be used to finance this support for poorer households and it can also be used to pay for additional measures that slow down climate change and support environmental regeneration: including <a href="https://ourworldindata.org/afforestation">reforestation</a>, more walkable and cyclable cities, or research and development for renewable energy and low-carbon technologies. </p><p>With a carbon price one can establish a mechanism that ensures that those who are causing emissions are those who pay for the countermeasures that benefit society and the environment.</p></div><div class="wp-block-column"></div></div><div class="wp-block-columns is-style-sticky-right"><div class="wp-block-column"><h4 id="a-carbon-price-allows-us-to-make-two-decisions">A carbon price allows us to make two decisions<a class="deep-link" href="#a-carbon-price-allows-us-to-make-two-decisions"></a></h4></div><div class="wp-block-column"></div></div><div class="wp-block-columns is-style-sticky-right"><div class="wp-block-column"><p>Levying a monetary price on emissions allows us to choose our answer to two important questions: <em>Who</em> should pay the price for carbon emissions? <em>How much</em> do we want them to pay for emitting greenhouse gases?</p><h5><em>Who</em> should pay the price for emitting greenhouse gases?</h5><p>At the most fundamental level the argument for carbon pricing is the hard truth that we have to pay a price for carbon emissions. What we can decide is who pays for them.</p><p>The status quo in a society without carbon pricing could not be more brutal:</p><ul><li>The people who live in high-income countries – those who enjoy the best living conditions in human history – are those who will be least affected by climate change, yet they are <a href="https://ourworldindata.org/worlds-energy-problem">the ones with the highest emissions</a>.</li><li>The people who will be most affected by the negative consequences of a hotter planet are those that have contributed the least to climate change: the poorest people in the world – who are at risk of increasing food insecurity and do not have the resources to adapt to changes as rapidly – and the generations that come after us.</li></ul><p>Without a monetary price on carbon it is those who have the lowest emissions that pay the most. </p><p>With carbon pricing we make sure that those who cause emissions also pay for them.</p><p>Because emissions rise with income, a carbon price ensures that it will be the rich who pay most.<a id="ref-9" class="ref" href="#note-9"><sup>9</sup></a> For the very rich it is the case that a few consumption choices – flights, large cars, meat – are responsible for the bulk of their emissions.<a id="ref-10" class="ref" href="#note-10"><sup>10</sup></a> Carbon pricing is a policy targeted to address these consumption choices, it makes carbon-intensive goods less affordable and ‘degrows’ the consumption of those goods.</p><h5><em>How much</em> do we make people pay for emitting greenhouse gases? </h5><p>The second decision that we can influence with a price on carbon is: <em>How much</em> do we want to pay for fossil fuels? </p><p>If we continue emitting high volumes of greenhouse gases we will cause severe climate change and eventually have to pay a high price from the damages. Several studies find that if we don’t achieve a reduction in emissions now, economic growth would be much lower in the decades ahead (and that surely wouldn’t be our main concern in such a future).<a id="ref-11" class="ref" href="#note-11"><sup>11</sup></a> </p><p>Levying a fee on carbon emissions can be a key policy to bring down emissions quickly so that we avoid large costs in the future.</p><p>In the past many macroeconomists considered the need to cut emissions as a drag on the economy that lowers economic growth. This idea, that decarbonisation of our economies conflicts with economic growth, is still shared by many.<a id="ref-12" class="ref" href="#note-12"><sup>12</sup></a></p><p>But this is no longer the mainstream view. The latest annual IMF report estimates that policies, including carbon pricing, that mitigate climate change actually <em>increase</em> economic growth over the coming decades.<a id="ref-13" class="ref" href="#note-13"><sup>13</sup></a> This means that there is no trade-off between fighting climate change and economic growth. Fighting climate change is a way to achieve <em>more growth</em>.<a id="ref-14" class="ref" href="#note-14"><sup>14</sup></a> </p><p>From the responses to my recent writing on <a href="https://ourworldindata.org/poverty-minimum-growth-needed">the need of growth for ending poverty</a> I saw that some people have not caught up with this. Fighting climate change is not just compatible with fighting poverty, the two goals — to reduce emissions and to increase economic growth — actually <em>strengthen</em> each other.</p><p>It is very good news that fighting climate change is expected to increase growth over the coming decades, but the benefits to climate mitigation are larger than just additional growth: it also means a modernisation of key infrastructure, faster innovation, the protection of the biosphere on our planet, and the major health benefits of reduced air pollution caused by burning fossil fuels, including millions of lives saved. </p><p>Taking both the costs and benefits into account makes a very clear argument for climate action now. Putting a price on carbon to build a low-carbon world is an investment for a much better future.</p></div><div class="wp-block-column"></div></div><div class="wp-block-columns is-style-sticky-right"><div class="wp-block-column"><h4 id="for-once-even-economists-agree">For once even economists agree<a class="deep-link" href="#for-once-even-economists-agree"></a></h4></div><div class="wp-block-column"></div></div><div class="wp-block-columns is-style-sticky-right"><div class="wp-block-column"><p>Economists are not known for agreeing much with one another. But regarding the challenge of how to reduce greenhouse gas emissions there is more agreement among economists than in perhaps any other big policy question. </p><p>What is particularly encouraging is that this is a policy that is supported by both left- and right-leaning economists. That left-leaning economists are in favour of a tax that will mostly be paid for by richer people is not surprising. It is perhaps more surprising that many right-leaning economists – who are generally in favor of a small state with only minimal taxes – are also in favor. Economists on the conservative side of the spectrum, such as Greg Mankiw, <a href="https://scholar.harvard.edu/files/mankiw/files/smart_taxes.pdf">advocate strongly for a carbon tax</a> and widespread support for carbon taxes of economists across the political spectrum is documented in many relevant surveys.<a id="ref-15" class="ref" href="#note-15"><sup>15</sup></a> </p><p>An alternative to a carbon price that many governments pursue is to rely on specific guidelines, but doing this well is an incredibly difficult task. A government with the goal to reduce emissions can try to regulate each specific sector and decide which types of production and consumption should be reduced or forbidden. But the planner who is tasked with doing this needs to have an enormous knowledge of all kinds of technologies, their carbon footprint, their cost, the possible alternatives, and their future potential. The carbon price is such an effective alternative to the central planner, because it doesn’t require a central authority to have enormous knowledge. Instead it incentivizes everyone to reduce carbon emissions – since they are incentivized to save money – and thereby distributes the task of reducing emissions to <em>everyone</em> – every producer, every investor, every consumer. Instead of one central agency, it incentivizes billions of people to search for ways to reduce their costs and thereby to find millions of solutions to reduce their emissions.</p><p>Another aspect that is convincing even to those who favour a small state is that if you want to have <em>any public spending at all</em> – and very few want a state that is so small that neither roads nor the police are publicly funded – you have to raise state revenue <em>somewhere</em>. The argument then is that if you have to have some taxes, it’s better to tax something that harms people rather than something that we want to encourage, like work. There are big losers from a carbon price – the fossil fuel industry – but for citizens, the overall taxes do not have to increase: the carbon price is government revenue so that it can reduce taxes elsewhere. It is actually the other way around: the implicit subsidies to fossil fuels are costly and thereby increase taxes for everyone – as we have seen, the IMF estimates that the lack of carbon pricing means that governments lose 3.8% of GDP and this loss either means greater public debt or it has to be made up by all of us paying higher taxes.</p><p>Poorer households spend a larger share of their income on energy so that a carbon price would hit these households hardest. It is possible to avoid this consequence by making the poorest households benefit from the spending that the carbon tax allows. The famous call for a carbon tax signed by a large number of leading economists at <a href="https://www.econstatement.org/">econstatement.org</a> has this goal. “To maximize the fairness and political viability of a rising carbon tax, all the revenue should be returned directly to U.S. citizens through equal lump-sum rebates. The majority of American families, including the most vulnerable, will benefit financially by receiving more in ‘carbon dividends’ than they pay in increased energy prices.”</p></div><div class="wp-block-column"></div></div><div class="wp-block-columns is-style-sticky-right"><div class="wp-block-column"><h4 id="what-is-stopping-us">What is stopping us?<a class="deep-link" href="#what-is-stopping-us"></a></h4></div><div class="wp-block-column"></div></div><div class="wp-block-columns is-style-sticky-right"><div class="wp-block-column"><p>The world did make a start on carbon pricing. 78 different jurisdictions have implemented a carbon price and this year (2021) a price will be paid on 22% of the world’s carbon emissions.<a id="ref-16" class="ref" href="#note-16"><sup>16</sup></a> 17 years ago a price was paid on much less than 1% of all emissions.</p><p>But the carbon price is low in many places and the figures just cited mean that there is no monetary price on three-quarters of emissions.</p><p>Given all the arguments above, why is effective carbon pricing not implemented in many more places? </p><p>A big reason is of course that those that will lose out from carbon pricing – the fossil fuel industry – rally against them. </p><p>But it is also the case that carbon pricing is not very popular among voters. Study after study finds that a key reason for this is that <em>many do not believe that a price on carbon is actually effective in reducing emissions</em>.<a id="ref-17" class="ref" href="#note-17"><sup>17</sup></a> While it is the effectiveness of carbon prices that makes them popular among experts, it is the perceived ineffectiveness that makes them unpopular among non-experts. </p><p>But it is also the case that people change their mind about carbon prices when they learn that they do actually work.<a id="ref-18" class="ref" href="#note-18"><sup>18</sup></a> After the Swiss population rejected a carbon price in a referendum, a group of researchers – Carattini et al (2017)<a id="ref-19" class="ref" href="#note-19"><sup>19</sup></a> – ran a study to investigate what could have made the proposal more popular. They found that “the effectiveness of energy taxes is not an established fact for the general public” and their study showed that the most important successful argument in favour of the tax is information on the expected effectiveness in reducing emissions.</p><p>It shouldn’t be surprising that the communication of successful strategies is of such great importance. Many of us care a lot about climate change – people around the world <a href="https://www.pewresearch.org/global/2020/09/09/despite-pandemic-many-europeans-still-see-climate-change-as-greatest-threat-to-their-countries/">consistently view</a> it as one of the largest challenges that humanity faces – and at the same time many feel hopeless that we can actually do anything about it. Showing that there <em>is</em> a way forward is key for the successful fight against climate change.</p></div><div class="wp-block-column"></div></div><div class="wp-block-columns is-style-sticky-right"><div class="wp-block-column"><h4 id="empirical-evidence-does-a-price-on-carbon-reduce-carbon-emissions">Empirical evidence: Does a price on carbon reduce carbon emissions?<a class="deep-link" href="#empirical-evidence-does-a-price-on-carbon-reduce-carbon-emissions"></a></h4></div><div class="wp-block-column"></div></div><div class="wp-block-columns is-style-sticky-right"><div class="wp-block-column"><p>Back in 1991 Sweden was one of the first countries in the world to implement a carbon tax. Over time the carbon tax was gradually increased, but it still mainly affects the transport sector (around 90 percent of the revenues from the carbon tax come from the consumption of gasoline and motor diesel).<a id="ref-20" class="ref" href="#note-20"><sup>20</sup></a></p><p>The researcher Julius Andersson studied whether the carbon price worked as intended by studying its impact on emissions from the transport sector.<a id="ref-21" class="ref" href="#note-21"><sup>21</sup></a> </p><p>He finds that “CO<sub>2</sub> emissions from transport declined almost 11 percent in an average year, with 6 percent from the carbon tax alone.” A very strong effect.</p><p>How did prosperity and emissions change in Sweden over this period? The chart for Sweden, in the top left corner, gives the answer. Average incomes in Sweden increased by 52% since the year before the tax was introduced, and emissions declined by 29%.<a id="ref-22" class="ref" href="#note-22"><sup>22</sup></a> </p><p>Shown in the chart are consumption-based CO<sub>2</sub> emissions, which means that they account for the carbon emissions caused by products that were consumed in Sweden, but which were produced in other countries. The 29% decline of emissions shows that Swedes are consuming goods that are produced with less and less fossil fuels.</p><p>Sweden’s emissions are still far from where they need to be, but the direction of change – growing prosperity, but declining emissions – is right. </p><p>And Sweden is not the only country that reduced emissions while growing the economy, as the chart shows.<a id="ref-23" class="ref" href="#note-23"><sup>23</sup></a></p><p>Carbon pricing is not the only reason emissions are falling in these countries. As we just saw, the paper on Sweden attributes about half of the decline to the carbon tax. Other reasons include technological progress (such as rising efficiency and <a href="https://ourworldindata.org/cheap-renewables-growth">cheaper renewables</a>), declining demand for energy, and other regulations (for example, on air pollution). </p><p>Like all policies that are based on a price mechanism, the level of the price matters. If it is too low it won’t have much of an effect. This is what Felix Pretis (2020) has found for the carbon tax in British Columbia.<a id="ref-24" class="ref" href="#note-24"><sup>24</sup></a></p><p>But in places that have a substantial carbon price, they can play an important role in reducing emissions, as a number of studies have shown.</p><p>In a recent global study, researchers Best, Burke, and Jotzo (2020) analysed 142 countries and found that those that have a carbon price do, as one would expect, have lower CO<sub>2</sub> emissions than those who do not.<a id="ref-25" class="ref" href="#note-25"><sup>25</sup></a></p><p>Germany too reduced emissions while becoming richer. The research by Petrick and Wagner (2014) showed how EU-wide carbon pricing contributed to this achievement.<a id="ref-26" class="ref" href="#note-26"><sup>26</sup></a> </p><p>Countries in the European Union have established a cap-and-trade system called the <a href="https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/European_Union_Emission_Trading_Scheme">EU Emission Trading Scheme</a> (EU ETS). Recent research by Bayer and Akin showed that this system of carbon pricing has been effective in reducing emissions.<a id="ref-27" class="ref" href="#note-27"><sup>27</sup></a> </p><p>Lastly, let’s look at the motherland of fossil-fuel-powered industrialization: the chart shows the sources of power production in the UK over the last century. </p><p>Electricity production in the UK has been dominated by coal since its early days; as soon as the light bulb was invented, the UK had its first coal power plant, the Holborn Viaduct power station in London. But this changed in recent decades, and especially rapidly after the UK introduced two carbon price systems. </p><p>The UK was already part of the EU ETS, but went even further in 2013 when the country implemented the ‘carbon price floor’: <a href="https://www.carbonbrief.org/unpopular-but-tenacious-a-guide-to-the-uk-carbon-price-floor">a top-up carbon tax</a> to the European system. </p><p>In the decade before the tax was introduced one third of electricity in the UK came from coal, <a href="https://ourworldindata.org/safest-sources-of-energy">the worst of power sources</a>. Since then the carbon tax “has led to an unprecedented reduction in coal generation” according to the research of Castagneto et al (2019).<a id="ref-28" class="ref" href="#note-28"><sup>28</sup></a> In the years following the policy change, the share of electricity generated from coal declined to just 2%.<a id="ref-29" class="ref" href="#note-29"><sup>29</sup></a> </p><p>As the share of electricity from fossil fuel sources declined, the carbon intensity of electricity production <a href="https://ourworldindata.org/grapher/carbon-intensity-electricity?tab=chart&time=2000..latest&country=~GBR">more than halved</a> and carbon emissions from power generation have <a href="https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/972583/2020_Provisional_emissions_statistics_report.pdf">fallen <em>by two-thirds</em></a> in the UK!</p><p>The Law of Demand – if the price of something goes up, consumption goes down – also holds in this case. Places that have implemented a substantial carbon price are achieving the intended effect, the consumption of carbon-intensive products declines and emissions fall.</p></div><div class="wp-block-column"><figure class="wp-block-image size-full"><img loading="lazy" width="2485" height="1488" src="https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2021/05/Absolute-decoupling-Growth-and-falling-emissions-1.png" alt="Absolute decoupling growth and falling emissions 1" class="wp-image-43249" srcset="https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2021/05/Absolute-decoupling-Growth-and-falling-emissions-1.png 2485w, https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2021/05/Absolute-decoupling-Growth-and-falling-emissions-1-400x240.png 400w, https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2021/05/Absolute-decoupling-Growth-and-falling-emissions-1-800x479.png 800w, https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2021/05/Absolute-decoupling-Growth-and-falling-emissions-1-150x90.png 150w, https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2021/05/Absolute-decoupling-Growth-and-falling-emissions-1-768x460.png 768w, https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2021/05/Absolute-decoupling-Growth-and-falling-emissions-1-1536x920.png 1536w, https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2021/05/Absolute-decoupling-Growth-and-falling-emissions-1-2048x1226.png 2048w" sizes="(max-width: 2485px) 100vw, 2485px" data-high-res-src="https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2021/05/Absolute-decoupling-Growth-and-falling-emissions-1.png"></figure></div></div><div class="wp-block-columns is-style-sticky-right">
<div class="wp-block-column">
<figure data-grapher-src="https://ourworldindata.org/grapher/electricity-mix-uk?country=~GBR" class="grapherPreview">
<a href="https://ourworldindata.org/grapher/electricity-mix-uk?country=~GBR" target="_blank">
<div><img src="https://ourworldindata.org/exports/electricity-mix-uk-46e63aafcfa0b805463e9bfef3f2ed51_v9_850x600.svg" width="850" height="600" loading="lazy" data-no-lightbox="" alt="Electricity mix uk 46e63aafcfa0b805463e9bfef3f2ed51 v9 850x600"></div>
<div class="interactionNotice">
<span class="icon"><svg aria-hidden="true" focusable="false" data-prefix="fas" data-icon="hand-pointer" class="svg-inline--fa fa-hand-pointer fa-w-14" role="img" xmlns="http://www.w3.org/2000/svg" viewBox="0 0 448 617">
<path fill="currentColor" d="M448,344.59v96a40.36,40.36,0,0,1-1.06,9.16l-32,136A40,40,0,0,1,376,616.59H168a40,40,0,0,1-32.35-16.47l-128-176a40,40,0,0,1,64.7-47.06L104,420.58v-276a40,40,0,0,1,80,0v200h8v-40a40,40,0,1,1,80,0v40h8v-24a40,40,0,1,1,80,0v24h8a40,40,0,1,1,80,0Zm-256,80h-8v96h8Zm88,0h-8v96h8Zm88,0h-8v96h8Z" transform="translate(0 -0.41)"></path>
<path fill="currentColor" opacity="0.6" d="M239.76,234.78A27.5,27.5,0,0,1,217,192a87.76,87.76,0,1,0-145.9,0A27.5,27.5,0,1,1,25.37,222.6,142.17,142.17,0,0,1,1.24,143.17C1.24,64.45,65.28.41,144,.41s142.76,64,142.76,142.76a142.17,142.17,0,0,1-24.13,79.43A27.47,27.47,0,0,1,239.76,234.78Z" transform="translate(0 -0.41)"></path>
</svg></span>
<span class="label">Click to open interactive version</span>
</div>
</a>
</figure>
</div>
<div class="wp-block-column"></div>
</div><div class="wp-block-columns is-style-sticky-right"><div class="wp-block-column"><div class="block-wrapper"><div class="wp-block-owid-prominent-link with-image" data-no-lightbox="true" data-style="is-style-thin" data-title="Shrink emissions, not the economy"><a href="https://ourworldindata.org/shrink-emissions-not-the-economy"><figure><img width="768" height="542" src="https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2018/04/value-added-vs-share-of-emissions-usa-1-768x542.png" class="attachment-medium_large size-medium_large" alt="Value added vs share of emissions usa 1" loading="lazy" srcset="https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2018/04/value-added-vs-share-of-emissions-usa-1-768x542.png 768w, https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2018/04/value-added-vs-share-of-emissions-usa-1-150x106.png 150w, https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2018/04/value-added-vs-share-of-emissions-usa-1-400x282.png 400w, https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2018/04/value-added-vs-share-of-emissions-usa-1-750x529.png 750w" sizes="(max-width: 768px) 100vw, 768px" data-high-res-src="https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2018/04/value-added-vs-share-of-emissions-usa-1.png"></figure><div class="content-wrapper"><div class="content">
<p><em>If you want to understand why it is possible to reduce emissions while growing the economy, see this Our World in Data guest post by Linus Mattauch, Alexander Radebach, Jan Siegmeier, and Simona Sulikova that answers this question.</em></p>
</div><div class="title"><span>Shrink emissions, not the economy</span><svg aria-hidden="true" focusable="false" data-prefix="fas" data-icon="arrow-right" class="svg-inline--fa fa-arrow-right " role="img" xmlns="http://www.w3.org/2000/svg" viewBox="0 0 448 512"><path fill="currentColor" d="M438.6 278.6l-160 160C272.4 444.9 264.2 448 256 448s-16.38-3.125-22.62-9.375c-12.5-12.5-12.5-32.75 0-45.25L338.8 288H32C14.33 288 .0016 273.7 .0016 256S14.33 224 32 224h306.8l-105.4-105.4c-12.5-12.5-12.5-32.75 0-45.25s32.75-12.5 45.25 0l160 160C451.1 245.9 451.1 266.1 438.6 278.6z"></path></svg></div></div></a></div></div></div><div class="wp-block-column"></div></div><div class="wp-block-columns is-style-sticky-right"><div class="wp-block-column"><h4 id="conclusion">Conclusion<a class="deep-link" href="#conclusion"></a></h4></div><div class="wp-block-column"></div></div><div class="wp-block-columns is-style-sticky-right"><div class="wp-block-column"><p>What’s frustrating about the challenge of climate change is not that we have no options, but that we do not take the options we have. </p><p>The reason our societies are powered by fossil fuels is that they provided energy at the cheapest monetary price. If we want to transition away from fossil fuels and build a world that is powered by their alternatives we can rely on the price mechanism as well.</p><p>What makes carbon pricing so powerful is that it is a policy that changes the entire system. No decision about any carbon-intensive activity escapes its influence: it changes the choices of consumers, producers, investors, entrepreneurs and innovators in all relevant sectors at once. </p><p>I want to make clear that I do not believe that carbon pricing can be the one policy change that will end climate change.<a id="ref-30" class="ref" href="#note-30"><sup>30</sup></a> But the theory and evidence is clear that carbon prices work as intended and if we are able to end climate change in this century I would be surprised if we achieve this without putting a price on carbon. In other words, I don’t think this is sufficient, but I do think it would be a key step towards a better future.</p><p>Our challenge is big. We need to build a new world that still solves the problems that fossil fuels solve today. Carbon-intensive goods and services are often in high demand today, because they are important for people. They have the unfortunate by-product of carbon emissions, but they solve other problems for us and everyone around us. Key to making the transition to a low-carbon future will be to innovate and scale-up alternatives. Carbon prices are useful for this transition because they give <em>everyone</em> an incentive to get there, especially in <a href="https://ourworldindata.org/cheap-renewables-growth">those sectors where alternatives <em>do</em> exist</a>. </p><p>And in those areas where low-carbon alternatives do not yet exist, support for research and development will be key. Because these two policies are working towards the same goal they <em>complement</em> each other, a higher price on carbon provides an incentive to increase R&D.</p><p>We<em> do</em> have options, and understanding them is not exactly rocket science. Consumption goes down, when prices go up. If we want to reduce carbon emissions we should not be paying people to burn fossil-fuels. We should end subsidies.</p><p>What is hard, is to win the necessary political support for pricing carbon. The article linked below draws the political lessons from places that were successful in establishing carbon prices.</p><p>I believe that putting a price on carbon is one of the most important goals to fight for in our lifetime. The current world is not sustainable and it is just not right that the richest have the highest emissions, while those who emit the least – the poorest and those who come after us – pay the highest price. Carbon pricing addresses the current injustice where we are allowing the richest to privately enjoy the gains from fossil fuels, while they pass off the costs to everyone else.</p><p>If we are serious about decarbonizing the global economy – and building the low-carbon future – we should make the fight for a monetary price on carbon central to our efforts over the years ahead.</p><hr class="wp-block-separator"><p><strong>Acknowledgements:</strong> I would like to thank Hannah Ritchie, Marcel Gerber, Charlie Giattino, Esteban Ortiz-Ospina for reading drafts of this text and for their very helpful comments and ideas.</p><div style="height:144px" aria-hidden="true" class="wp-block-spacer"></div><hr class="wp-block-separator"><p>If you want to think through the <strong>counterarguments to pricing carbon</strong>, here is a list of references to get you started with:</p><ul><li>One of the most widely discussed recent articles on the topic is <a href="https://bostonreview.net/science-nature-politics/leah-c-stokes-matto-mildenberger-trouble-carbon-pricing">The Trouble with Carbon Pricing</a> authored by Leah Stokes and Matto Mildenberger. As I emphasized above, the authors’ main point is that while carbon prices make economic and environmental sense, it is difficult to get the political support that they need to be free of loopholes and to be high enough to make a difference. They also argue that it would be wrong to believe that no other policy is needed to bring emissions to zero. I largely agree with the authors. Carbon taxes cannot be the only solution – they emphasise clean energy standards, I’d emphasise public R&D – but I disagree that this means we should not make it our political goal to put a price on carbon. I think they should be part of a big package of successful climate policy tools – carbon prices are one tool in our hands and we shouldn’t weaken ourselves by throwing away solutions that we do have.</li><li>Ramez Naam wrote <a href="https://twitter.com/ramez/status/1094380540394795008">this very good Twitter thread</a> on why carbon taxes are a good policy, but why he believes that subsidies for specific technologies can be even better in some cases.</li><li>Rosenbloom et al (2020) discuss the weaknesses of carbon pricing and offer their own alternative, which they call “sustainability transition policy”, a “mix of contextually and politically sensitive policies that simultaneously drive low-carbon innovation and the decline of fossil fuels”.<ul><li>Daniel Rosenbloom, Jochen Markard, Frank W. Geels, and Lea Fuenfschilling (2020) – <a href="https://www.pnas.org/content/117/16/8664.short">Opinion: Why carbon pricing is not sufficient to mitigate climate change—and how “sustainability transition policy” can help</a>. In PNAS.</li></ul><ul><li>I am personally not impressed by the Rosenbloom et al (2020) critique and agree largely with the reply by Jeroen van den Berg and Wouter Botzen (2020) also published in PNAS.</li><li>Jeroen van den Berg and Wouter Botzen (2020) – <a href="https://www.pnas.org/content/117/38/23219">Low-carbon transition is improbable without carbon pricing</a>, PNAS.</li></ul></li><li>Goulder et al. (2016) argue that implementing a closely related policy – a clean energy standard (CES) – can be more cost-effective than a carbon price.</li><li>Lawrence H. Goulder, Marc A. C. Hafstead, Roberton C. Williams III (2016) – General Equilibrium Impacts of a Federal Clean Energy Standard. In the American Economic Journal: Economic Policy. VOL. 8, NO. 2, MAY 2016. (pp. 186-218).</li><li>Three more pointers:<ul><li>Garth Heutel (2020) – <a href="https://econfip.org/policy-brief/in-defense-of-alternatives-to-pollution-pricing/#">In Defense of Alternatives to Pollution Pricing</a></li><li>See <a href="https://marginalrevolution.com/marginalrevolution/2011/09/do-all-serious-economists-favor-a-carbon-tax.html">this list of 10 arguments by Tyler Cowen</a>.</li><li>And finally I have also asked the question <a href="https://twitter.com/MaxCRoser/status/1326671354654023682">‘What are the best papers or essays with arguments against a carbon price?</a>’, publicly on Twitter. There are several helpful replies there.</li></ul></li></ul><hr class="wp-block-separator"><p><em>Continue reading on Our World in Data:</em></p><div class="block-wrapper"><div class="wp-block-owid-prominent-link with-image" data-no-lightbox="true" data-style="is-style-thin" data-title="Why is carbon pricing in some countries more successful than in others?"><a href="https://ourworldindata.org/carbon-pricing-popular"><figure><img width="768" height="431" src="https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2018/08/carbon-prices-public-trust-768x431.png" class="attachment-medium_large size-medium_large" alt="Carbon prices public trust" loading="lazy" srcset="https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2018/08/carbon-prices-public-trust-768x431.png 768w, https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2018/08/carbon-prices-public-trust-150x84.png 150w, https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2018/08/carbon-prices-public-trust-400x225.png 400w, https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2018/08/carbon-prices-public-trust-750x421.png 750w, https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2018/08/carbon-prices-public-trust.png 922w" sizes="(max-width: 768px) 100vw, 768px" data-high-res-src="https://ourworldindata.org/uploads/2018/08/carbon-prices-public-trust.png"></figure><div class="content-wrapper"><div class="content">
<p>In some countries the public is very supportive of carbon taxes. In other countries they are largely against them. </p>
</div><div class="title"><span>Why is carbon pricing in some countries more successful than in others?</span><svg aria-hidden="true" focusable="false" data-prefix="fas" data-icon="arrow-right" class="svg-inline--fa fa-arrow-right " role="img" xmlns="http://www.w3.org/2000/svg" viewBox="0 0 448 512"><path fill="currentColor" d="M438.6 278.6l-160 160C272.4 444.9 264.2 448 256 448s-16.38-3.125-22.62-9.375c-12.5-12.5-12.5-32.75 0-45.25L338.8 288H32C14.33 288 .0016 273.7 .0016 256S14.33 224 32 224h306.8l-105.4-105.4c-12.5-12.5-12.5-32.75 0-45.25s32.75-12.5 45.25 0l160 160C451.1 245.9 451.1 266.1 438.6 278.6z"></path></svg></div></div></a></div></div></div><div class="wp-block-column"></div></div></section>
</div><footer class="article-footer"><div class="wp-block-columns"><div class="wp-block-column"><div class="blog-info">
<p>Our World in Data presents the data and research to make progress against the world’s largest problems.<br>This post draws on data and research discussed in our entry on <strong><a href="https://ourworldindata.org/co2-and-other-greenhouse-gas-emissions" target="_blank" rel="noopener noreferrer">Greenhouse Gas Emissions</a></strong>. Minor changes and updates were made after the text was first published.</p>
</div><h3 id="endnotes">Endnotes</h3><ol class="endnotes"><li id="note-1"><p>See IPCC (2014) – <a href="https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/02/SYR_AR5_FINAL_full.pdf">Climate Change 2014: Synthesis Report</a>. Contribution of Working Groups I, II and III to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [Core Writing Team, R.K. Pachauri and L.A. Meyer (eds.)]. IPCC, Geneva, Switzerland, 151 pp.</p>
<ul><li>Box 2.2: “It is <em>very likely</em> that <strong>heat waves</strong> will occur more often and last longer, and that <strong>extreme precipitation</strong> events will become more intense and frequent in many regions. The ocean will <strong>continue to warm and acidify</strong>, and <strong>global mean sea level to rise</strong>.”</li><li>Box 2.3: “Risks are unevenly distributed and are generally greater for disadvantaged people and communities in countries at all levels of development.”</li></ul>
<p>On the risk to biodiversity see Urban, Mark C. (2015). <a href="https://science.sciencemag.org/content/348/6234/571">“Accelerating extinction risk from climate change”</a>. In Science. 348 (6234): 571–573.</p>
<p>For a larger overview see Wikipedia’s pages on the <a href="https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Effects_of_climate_change">Effects of Climate Change</a> and <a href="https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Climate_change#Effects">the relevant section on their page on climate change</a>.</p></li><li id="note-2"><p>In a study published in the Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, Jos Lelieveld et al. (2019) estimated that 5.6 million people died from anthropogenically caused air pollution. Of these 5.6 million, 3.6 million deaths were attributed to burning fossil fuels. </p>
<p>Lelieveld, J., Klingmüller, K., Pozzer, A., Burnett, R. T., Haines, A., & Ramanathan, V. (2019). <a href="https://www.pnas.org/content/116/15/7192/">Effects of fossil fuel and total anthropogenic emission removal on public health and climate</a>. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 116(15), 7192-7197<br><br>The death toll of the three counts of violence for 2017 <a href="https://ourworldindata.org/grapher/annual-number-of-deaths-by-cause">according to the IHME</a> is 561,511.<br>• Homicides: 405,346 deaths<br>• War battles: 129,720 deaths<br>• Terrorism: 26,445 deaths<br><br>The uncertainty of the death toll due to air pollution caused by burning fossil fuels is high. A very recent study – Vohra et al (2021) – estimates that 8.7 million deaths globally are due to the air pollution caused by burning fossil fuels.<br>Vohra, K., Vodonos, A., Schwartz, J., Marais, E. A., Sulprizio, M. P., & Mickley, L. J. (2021). Global mortality from outdoor fine particle pollution generated by fossil fuel combustion: Results from GEOS-Chem. <em>Environmental Research</em>, <em>195</em>, 110754.<a href="https://doi.org/10.1016/j.envres.2021.110754"> https://doi.org/10.1016/j.envres.2021.110754</a>.</p></li><li id="note-3"><p>The published study is: David Coady, Ian Parry, Louis Sears, Baoping Shang (2017) – How Large Are Global Fossil Fuel Subsidies? In World Development. Volume 91, March 2017, Pages 11-27. <a href="https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2016.10.004">https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2016.10.004</a><br><br>In 2019 the authors updated their previous research in David Coady, Ian Parry, Nghia-Piotr Le, and Baoping Shang (2019) – <a href="https://scholar.google.com/scholar?hl=en&as_sdt=0%2C5&q=doi.org%2F10.5089%2F9781484393178.001&btnG=">Global Fossil Fuel Subsidies Remain Large: An Update Based on Country-Level Estimates</a>. Published as an IMF Working Paper. </p>
<p>In my text I am citing the latest figures of the authors.<br><br>By fuel the subsidies were as follows in 2015: coal (44 percent), petroleum (41 percent), and natural gas (10 percent).<br>Coal: $5,200 billion * 0.44 = $2,288 billion<br>Oil: $5,200 billion * 0.41 = $2,132 billion<br>Natural gas: $5,200 billion * 0.1 = $520 billion</p>
<p>Subsidies to renewable power generation technologie amounts to US-$ 128 billion, biofuels to US-$ 38 billion and nuclear to at least US-$ 21 billion (the source notes that data on nuclear subsidies is lacking and states that “the subsidy value for nuclear in this analysis is a placeholder value, reflecting the lowest realistic level of subsidies for existing nuclear power generation.”, This data is according to the <a href="https://www.irena.org/-/media/Files/IRENA/Agency/Publication/2020/Apr/IRENA_Energy_subsidies_2020.pdf">International Renewable Energy Agency (2020) – Energy subsidies</a> Unfortunately this source does not break down the subsidies to renewables by source of energy.</p>
<p>The <a href="https://ourworldindata.org/grapher/energy-consumption-by-source-and-region?stackMode=absolute&time=earliest..latest">energy production from these sources</a> in 2019 is: Oil 53,260TWh, Coal 43,849TWh, Gas 39,292TWh, Nuclear 6923TWh, Renewables 18,504 TWh (1614+1102+1793+3540+10455).<br><br>This means the subsidy per TWh of energy is:<br>Coal: $2,288,000,000,000/43,849TWh = $ 52,179,069 per TWh<br>Oil: $2,132,000,000,000/53,260TWh = $40,030,041 per TWh<br>Gas: $520,000,000,000/39,292TWh = $13,234,246 per TWh<br>Renewables: $166,000,000,000/18,504TWh = $8,971,033 per TWh<br>Nuclear: $21,000,000,000/6923TWh = $3,033,367 per TWh</p>
<p>These are only explicit subsidies and the fact that renewables and nuclear energy do cause deaths and environmental damage means that these sources too are implicitly subsidised (although much less than fossil fuels). On the other hand it is worth keeping in mind that reducing subsidies to fossil fuels would remove one of the key motivations for renewable energy subsidies.<br><br>What I am calling explicit subsidies is called “pre-tax subsidies” by these authors. What I am calling implicit subsidies is called “post-tax subsidies” by these authors. </p></li><li id="note-4"><p>One way to think about the distinction between explicit and implicit subsidies is that for the former the government has to pay costs from the available budget, in the latter the prices are suppressed, it is the lack of charging that is the cost.<br><br>An alternative framing would be to rely on the concept of externalities. The negative impact on others as a result of the production or consumption of a product is called a negative externality. An implicit subsidy in this framing is any negative externality for which those who cause the externality do not have to pay for.</p></li><li id="note-5"><p>The IMF study estimates that pricing fossil fuel efficiently would lower global carbon emissions by 28 percent, fossil fuel air pollution deaths by 46 percent, and increase government revenue by 3.8 percent of GDP. But as with any such estimates the precise numbers depend strongly on the assumptions made. Placing a value on the benefits of reducing emissions is very hard (what is the value of saving a threatened species?). But the point is that whatever the precise values might be, it’s undeniable that the costs are very large.</p></li><li id="note-6"><p>The <a href="https://www.core-econ.org/the-economy/book/text/12.html">free online textbook CORE ECON</a> provides clear and complete definitions of externalities, as well as policy choices in the context of environmental problems.</p></li><li id="note-7"><p>Some alternatives to carbon taxes and cap and trade – such as clean energy standards or regulations – can be viewed as implicit prices on carbon emissions.</p>
<p>It’s a core result in resource economics that both cap and trade and taxes can be designed to be equivalent. Much more information about both carbon pricing approaches can be found in CORE ECON <a href="https://www.core-econ.org/the-economy/book/text/20.html">here</a>.</p></li><li id="note-8"><p>Klenert, D., Mattauch, L., Combet, E., Edenhofer, O., Hepburn, C., Rafaty, R., Stern, N. (2018) – <a href="https://www.nature.com/articles/s41558-018-0201-2?WT.feed_name=subjects_economics">Making Carbon Pricing Work for Citizens</a>. In Nature Climate Change 8, 669–677.</p></li><li id="note-9"><p>That they pay the most is a statement about absolute spending. As explained below, the <em>relative</em> spending on energy is often highest for poorer households.</p></li><li id="note-10"><p>Ivanova D, Wood R (2020). The unequal distribution of household carbon footprints in Europe and its link to sustainability. Global Sustainability 3, e18, 1–12. <a href="https://doi.org/10.1017/sus.2020.12">https://doi.org/10.1017/sus.2020.12</a>.</p></li><li id="note-11"><p>On the relation between future warming and growth see:<br>Pretis, F., Schwarz, M., Tang, K., Haustein, K., & Allen, M. R. (2018). Uncertain impacts on economic growth when stabilizing global temperatures at 1.5°C or 2°C warming. <em>Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society A: Mathematical, Physical and Engineering Sciences</em>, <em>376</em>(2119), 20160460.<a href="https://doi.org/10.1098/rsta.2016.0460"> https://doi.org/10.1098/rsta.2016.0460<br></a></p>
<p>Burke, M., Hsiang, S. M., & Miguel, E. (2015). Global non-linear effect of temperature on economic production. <em>Nature</em>, <em>527</em>(7577), 235–239.<a href="https://doi.org/10.1038/nature15725"> https://doi.org/10.1038/nature15725</a> </p></li><li id="note-12"><p>In <a href="https://ourworldindata.org/shrink-emissions-not-the-economy">a guest post for Our World in Data</a> Linus Mattauch, Alexander Radebach, Jan Siegmeier, and Simona Sulikova put it like this:<br><em>“Ironically, the proponents of this claim come from two antagonistic camps. On the one hand, there are those who believe that addressing climate change must take priority and that this requires an organised diminution of economic output (termed “degrowth”). On the other hand, there are those who believe that economic growth and the social stability that comes with it should be prioritised: concerning oneself with climate policy should not be a priority if it impacts competitiveness.”</em></p></li><li id="note-13"><p><a href="https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WEO/Issues/2020/09/30/world-economic-outlook-october-2020">World Economic Outlook, October 2020: A Long and Difficult Ascent</a>. In October 2020. Their central point estimate is a boost of up to 13% of global GDP by 2100.</p></li><li id="note-14"><p>Even the last IPCC report (published 6 years ago) did not suggest that the antagonism of growth vs climate is correct. The IPCC report lays out what the cost of limiting global warming to less than 2°C would be. The policy scenario for the 21st century that relies on carbon pricing and technological innovation corresponds to an annualized reduction of economic growth by 0.06%, <em>relative to a baseline growth of 1.6% to 3%</em>. </p>
<p>In other words, if the world economy would grow at 1.6% per year, the world economy in 100 years would be 1.016^100=489% the size of today’s economy. With measures in place to limit warming to 2°C, growth would be 0.06% smaller – i.e. 1.54% per year. The world economy would then ‘only’ be 461% of the size of today.<br><br>In case the world economy would grow 3% per year the world economy in 100 years would be 1.03^100=1922% the size of today’s economy. With measures to limit warming to 2°C, growth would be 0.06% smaller – i.e. 2.94% per year. The economy would then ‘only’ be 1813% the size of today.</p>
<p>This is to say that the IPCC report in 2014 found rapid economic growth compatible with limiting climate change to 2°C.<br><br>The opposite is of course not true. While more climate mitigation in the short-term raises growth over the mid-term, it is not the case that more growth necessarily leads to lower greenhouse gas emissions.<br><br>See:<br>Edenhofer et al. (2014). <a href="https://www.ipcc.ch/report/ar5/wg3/">IPCC, 2014: Summary for Policymakers</a>. In: Climate Change 2014: Mitigation of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change.<br><br>See also: IPCC (2014) – <a href="https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/02/SYR_AR5_FINAL_full.pdf">Climate Change 2014: Synthesis Report</a>. Contribution of Working Groups I, II and III to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [Core Writing Team, R.K. Pachauri and L.A. Meyer (eds.)]. IPCC, Geneva, Switzerland, 151 pp.<br><br><a href="https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0095069617308707">https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0095069617308707</a><br></p></li><li id="note-15"><p>The IGM economic experts panel at Chicago Booth, which surveys a large number of leading economists at US universities, has repeatedly <a href="https://www.igmchicago.org/?s=carbon+tax">asked them about their opinion on a carbon tax</a> and invariably finds large support for such a tax.</p>
<p>See also the survey of 365 economists who have published papers related to climate change “in a highly ranked, peer-reviewed economics or environmental economics journal” conducted by The Institute for Policy Integrity at the New York University (NYU) School of Law. Published <a href="https://policyintegrity.org/files/publications/ExpertConsensusReport.pdf">here</a>. (Note also that, compared with the general public, a much larger share of economists believes that climate change is a very serious problem and that it is time to act now – see Figure 2a.)</p>
<p>In a 2006 survey of the American Economic Association, 65% agreed that “the US should increase energy taxes”.<br>Whaples, Robert. 2006. Do Economists Agree on Anything? Yes! The Economists’ Voice, 3(9).</p>
<p>The Wall Street Journal asked business economists in 2007, ‘‘What is the most economically sound way for the government to encourage development of alternatives to fossil fuels?’’ 54 percent advocated for ‘‘taxes that raise the cost of purchasing fossil fuels’’.<br>Izzo, Phil. 2007. Is It time for a New Tax on Energy? Wall Street Journal, February 9, 2007.</p>
<p>Keohane, M. N. O., & Olmstead, S. M. (2016). Markets and the Environment. Island Press, Washington.<br>Last year over 3,500 economists, including twenty-seven Nobel laureates, signed <a href="https://clcouncil.org/economists-statement/">this letter supporting carbon pricing</a>.</p></li><li id="note-16"><p>All data points and references here refer to the 2020 issue: World Bank (2020) – <a href="https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/33809">State and Trends of Carbon Pricing 2020</a>. Washington, DC: World Bank. © World Bank. License: CC BY 3.0 IGO.</p></li><li id="note-17"><p>See Stefano Carattini, Andrea Baranzini, Philippe Thalmann, Frédéric Varone, and Frank Vöhringer (2017) – “Green Taxes in a Post-Paris World: Are Millions of Nays Inevitable?” Environ Resource Econ 68, 97–128 (2017). <a href="https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-017-0133-8.%7B/ref">https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-017-0133-8</a><br><br>Baranzini A, Carattini S (2017) – Effectiveness, earmarking and labeling: testing the acceptability of carbon taxes with survey data. Environ Econ Policy Stud 19(1):197–227</p>
<p>and Klenert, D., Mattauch, L., Combet, E., Edenhofer, O., Hepburn, C., Rafaty, R., Stern, N. (2018) – <a href="https://www.nature.com/articles/s41558-018-0201-2?WT.feed_name=subjects_economics">Making Carbon Pricing Work for Citizens</a>. In Nature Climate Change 8, 669–677. </p></li><li id="note-18"><p>Klenert, D., Mattauch, L., Combet, E., Edenhofer, O., Hepburn, C., Rafaty, R., Stern, N. (2018) – <a href="https://www.nature.com/articles/s41558-018-0201-2?WT.feed_name=subjects_economics">Making Carbon Pricing Work for Citizens</a>. In Nature Climate Change 8, 669–677. </p></li><li id="note-19"><p>Stefano Carattini, Andrea Baranzini, Philippe Thalmann, Frédéric Varone, and Frank Vöhringer (2017) – “Green Taxes in a Post-Paris World: Are Millions of Nays Inevitable?” Environ Resource Econ 68, 97–128 (2017). <a href="https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-017-0133-8.%7B/ref">https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-017-0133-8</a> </p></li><li id="note-20"><p>The transport sector is of significant importance for Sweden’s carbon emissions: in the study period it was responsible for close to 40 percent of Sweden’s total annual CO<sub>2</sub> emissions.</p></li><li id="note-21"><p>Julius J. Andersson (2019) – <a href="https://pubs.aeaweb.org/doi/pdfplus/10.1257/pol.20170144">Carbon Taxes and CO2 Emissions: Sweden as a Case Study</a>. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy. 11 (4): 1–30. doi:10.1257/pol.20170144. ISSN 1945-7731.</p></li><li id="note-22"><p>In <a href="https://ourworldindata.org/grapher/consumption-co2-per-capita-vs-gdppc?endpointsOnly=1&time=2017..latest">this scatterplot of CO2 emissions vs GDP per capita</a> you can see Sweden in context. At annual emissions of 7.1 tonnes per capita the country is doing much better than other rich (and poor) countries.</p></li><li id="note-23"><p><a href="https://ourworldindata.org/grapher/co2-emissions-and-gdp?time=1990..latest&country=~SWE">In the interactive version of this chart</a> you can view this data for many more countries.</p></li><li id="note-24"><p>The recently introduced carbon price reduced emissions in the transport sector, but not on the wider economy. Pretis argues that this is because “existing carbon taxes (and prices) are too low to be effective in the time frame since their introduction.”</p>
<p>Felix Pretis (2020) – Does a carbon tax reduce CO2 emissions? Evidence from British Columbia. Working paper, published at the Department of Economics, University of Victoria & Nuffield College, University of Oxford. First Manuscript Version: Feb. 8th, 2019; This Version: Feb. 4, 2020.</p></li><li id="note-25"><p>Best, R., Burke, P.J. & Jotzo, F. (2020) – Carbon Pricing Efficacy: Cross-Country Evidence. Environ Resource Econ 77, 69–94. <a href="https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-020-00436-x">https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-020-00436-x</a> </p></li><li id="note-26"><p>Petrick, S., Wagner, U. J. (2014). The impact of carbon trading on industry: Evidence from German manufacturing firms, Kiel Working Paper, No. 1912, Kiel Institute for the World Economy (IfW), Kiel. <a href="https://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:zbw:ifwkwp:1912">https://EconPapers.repec.org/RePEc:zbw:ifwkwp:1912</a>}</p></li><li id="note-27"><p> Bayer, Patrick; Aklin, Michaël (2020) – The European Union Emissions Trading System reduced CO2 emissions despite low prices. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. doi:10.1073/pnas.1918128117</p></li><li id="note-28"><p>G. Castagneto Gissey, B. Guo, D. Newbery, G. Lipman, L. Montoya, P. Dodds, M. Grubb, P. Ekins (2019) – <a href="https://www.ucl.ac.uk/bartlett/sustainable/sites/bartlett/files/ucl_report_ofgem_20102019_final.pdf">The value of international electricity trading</a>. UCL and University of Cambridge. </p>
<p>See also: Marion Leroutier (2021) – Carbon Pricing and Power Sector Decarbonisation: Evidence from the UK. In Journal of Environmental Economics and Management.</p></li><li id="note-29"><p>These days it is common that the UK runs for <a href="https://www.theguardian.com/environment/ng-interactive/2019/may/25/the-power-switch-tracking-britains-record-coal-free-run">months without any coal electricity</a> at all, and like many countries that have a carbon price the UK has also <a href="https://ourworldindata.org/grapher/co2-emissions-and-gdp?time=1990..latest">achieved</a> an absolute decoupling of growth and greenhouse gases: prosperity is up, emissions are down.</p></li><li id="note-30"><p>On this see for example Ryan Rafaty, Geoffroy Dolphin, and Felix Pretis (2020) – <a href="https://www.ineteconomics.org/research/research-papers/carbon-pricing-and-the-elasticity-of-co2-emissions">Carbon Pricing and the Elasticity of CO2 Emissions</a>. INET Working Paper.</p></li></ol><h3 id="licence">Reuse our work freely</h3><p>All visualizations, data, and code produced by Our World in Data are completely open access under the <a href="https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/" target="_blank" rel="noopener noreferrer">Creative Commons BY license</a>. You have the permission to use, distribute, and reproduce these in any medium, provided the source and authors are credited.</p><p>The data produced by third parties and made available by Our World in Data is subject to the license terms from the original third-party authors. We will always indicate the original source of the data in our documentation, so you should always check the license of any such third-party data before use and redistribution.</p><p>All of <a href="/how-to-use-our-world-in-data#how-to-embed-interactive-charts-in-your-article">our charts can be embedded</a> in any site.</p></div><div class="wp-block-column"></div></div></footer></div></div></div></article></main><div id="wpadminbar" style="display:none"><div class="quicklinks" id="wp-toolbar" role="navigation" aria-label="Toolbar"><ul id="wp-admin-bar-root-default" class="ab-top-menu"><li id="wp-admin-bar-site-name" class="menupop"><a class="ab-item" aria-haspopup="true" href="https://owid.cloud/wp/wp-admin">Wordpress</a></li> <li id="wp-admin-bar-edit"><a class="ab-item" href="https://owid.cloud/wp/wp-admin/post.php?post=43232&action=edit">Edit Page</a></li></ul></div></div><section class="donate-footer"><div class="wrapper"><div class="owid-row flex-align-center"><div class="owid-col owid-col--lg-3 owid-padding-bottom--sm-3"><p>Our World in Data is free and accessible for everyone.</p><p>Help us do this work by making a donation.</p></div><div class="owid-col owid-col--lg-1"><a href="/donate" class="owid-button donate-button" data-track-note="donate-footer"><span class="label">Donate now</span><span class="icon"><svg aria-hidden="true" focusable="false" data-prefix="fas" data-icon="angle-right" class="svg-inline--fa fa-angle-right " role="img" xmlns="http://www.w3.org/2000/svg" viewBox="0 0 256 512"><path fill="currentColor" d="M64 448c-8.188 0-16.38-3.125-22.62-9.375c-12.5-12.5-12.5-32.75 0-45.25L178.8 256L41.38 118.6c-12.5-12.5-12.5-32.75 0-45.25s32.75-12.5 45.25 0l160 160c12.5 12.5 12.5 32.75 0 45.25l-160 160C80.38 444.9 72.19 448 64 448z"></path></svg></span></a></div></div></div></section><footer class="site-footer"><div class="wrapper"><div class="owid-row"><div class="owid-col owid-col--lg-1"><ul><li><a href="/about" data-track-note="footer-navigation">About</a></li><li><a href="/about#contact" data-track-note="footer-navigation">Contact</a></li><li><a href="/feedback" data-track-note="footer-navigation">Feedback</a></li><li><a href="/jobs" data-track-note="footer-navigation">Jobs</a></li><li><a href="/funding" data-track-note="footer-navigation">Funding</a></li><li><a href="/about/how-to-use-our-world-in-data" data-track-note="footer-navigation">How to use</a></li><li><a href="/donate" data-track-note="footer-navigation">Donate</a></li><li><a href="/privacy-policy" data-track-note="footer-navigation">Privacy policy</a></li></ul></div><div class="owid-col owid-col--lg-1"><ul><li><a href="/blog" data-track-note="footer-navigation">Latest work</a></li><li><a href="/charts" data-track-note="footer-navigation">All charts</a></li></ul><ul><li><a href="https://twitter.com/OurWorldInData" data-track-note="footer-navigation">Twitter</a></li><li><a href="https://www.facebook.com/OurWorldinData" data-track-note="footer-navigation">Facebook</a></li><li><a href="https://instagram.com/ourworldindata_official" data-track-note="footer-navigation">Instagram</a></li><li><a href="https://github.com/owid" data-track-note="footer-navigation">GitHub</a></li><li><a href="/feed" data-track-note="footer-navigation">RSS Feed</a></li></ul></div><div class="owid-col owid-col--lg-1"><div class="logos"><a href="https://www.oxfordmartin.ox.ac.uk/global-development" class="partner-logo" data-track-note="footer-navigation"><img src="https://ourworldindata.org/oms-logo.svg" alt="Oxford Martin School logo" loading="lazy"/></a><a href="/owid-at-ycombinator" class="partner-logo" data-track-note="footer-navigation"><img src="https://ourworldindata.org/yc-logo.png" alt="Y Combinator logo" loading="lazy"/></a></div></div><div class="owid-col flex-2"><div class="legal"><p>Licenses: All visualizations, data, and articles produced by Our World in Data are open access under the <a href="https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/" target="_blank" rel="noopener noreferrer">Creative Commons BY license</a>. You have permission to use, distribute, and reproduce these in any medium, provided the source and authors are credited. All the software and code that we write is open source and made available via GitHub under the permissive <a href="https://github.com/owid/owid-grapher/blob/master/LICENSE.md " target="_blank" rel="noopener noreferrer">MIT license</a>. All other material, including data produced by third parties and made available by Our World in Data, is subject to the license terms from the original third-party authors.</p><p>Please consult our full <a href="/about#legal">legal disclaimer</a>.</p><p><a href="https://global-change-data-lab.org/" class="partner-logo gcdl-logo" data-track-note="footer-navigation"><img src="https://ourworldindata.org/gcdl-logo.svg" alt="Global Change Data Lab logo" loading="lazy"/></a>Our World In Data is a project of the <a href="https://global-change-data-lab.org/">Global Change Data Lab</a>, a registered charity in England and Wales (Charity Number 1186433).</p></div></div></div></div><div class="site-tools"></div><script src="https://polyfill.io/v3/polyfill.min.js?features=es6,fetch,URL,IntersectionObserver,IntersectionObserverEntry"></script><script src="https://ourworldindata.org/assets/commons.js"></script><script src="https://ourworldindata.org/assets/vendors.js"></script><script src="https://ourworldindata.org/assets/owid.js"></script><script>window.runSiteFooterScripts()</script></footer><script>
runTableOfContents({"headings":[],"pageTitle":"The argument for a carbon price"})
runRelatedCharts(undefined)
</script></body></html>